Abstract
In many countries which have limited R&D budgets are confronted with discussions about the feasibility and appropriateness of supporting basic science and research. Among these countries is Austria – the country of origin of the authors. Basic research as opposed to applied research aims at increasing the stock of knowledgeper sewithout any consideration to applicability. Meanwhile, there is a widely held belief that publicly funded research must result in economic gains. Thus basic research is inherently under pressure of having to prove its favorable effects on the economy. In recent years such rhetoric has even intensified. Moreover the so-called ‘free-rider’ strategy presumes that it is ambiguous for a small economy to invest in costly basic research when the results of other countries’ basic research are published and available without charge as public goods.
The authors provide a retrospective analysis of the discussed issue. From his point of view rejection of developing country’s internal scientific base is reckless in terms of responsibility for the future of coming generations. Explaining the causes of way-out views, the authors offer a look at the situation from a different perspective paying attention to known facts.
Because of its high degree of specialization basic research is often thought of as abstract and out of touch with reality, but in the main it is inspired and set off by practical questions. Undoubtedly, an early estimate of its effects is quite complicated, since basic research outputs usually require a significant time lag to be transformed into commercial product. The authors suggest that in the future it will remain difficult to fully assess the impact of basic research on economic growth and to provide clear answers to the questions raised.
Numerous evidences however demonstrate that application of the knowledge gained from the basic research promotes the emergence of entirely new industrial developments. Basic science, supported by the government and development undertaken by the private sector, are able to be complementary and act in tandem. Today more than ever before there is a need for free, i.e. unrestricted, science-oriented research, namely for doing that part of research work which private companies can and will no longer afford. These projects contribute to the expansion of a company’s technological capacities by providing access to existing knowledge, guaranteeing the possibility of their use and further development, etc. It is proved that a country rejecting development of its own research facilities and skilled personnel will not be able to take advantage from the achievements gained by other nations. Availability of highly qualified and skilled scientists is essential for an efficient capture of new knowledge. Companies, possessing similar human capital, have the ability to absorb information from outside thus increasing in-house expertise.
The authors draw attention to the possibility for companies to conduct R&D in collaboration with universities. This will allow the commercialization of research results as well as investments in innovative entrepreneurial initiatives. In Austria, this type of funding so far remains underdeveloped.
References
Abramowitz M. (1989) Thinking about growth. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Aghion P., Howitt P. (1995) Research and development in the growth process // Journal of Economic Growth. Vol. 1. № 1. Р. 49-73.
Aghion P., Howitt P. (2009) The Economics of Growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Arrow K.J. (1962) Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Inventions / Nelson R. (ed.) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Bergman E.M. (1990) The economic impact of industry funded university R&D // Research Policy. Vol. 19. P. 340-355.
Cohen W., Levinthal D. (1989) Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D // Economic Journal. Vol. 99. P. 569-596.
Cowan R. (2005) Universities and the Knowledge Economy. MERIT-Infonomics Research Memorandum series. Maastricht.
Godin B. (2010) Innovation Studies: The Invention of the Speciality. Project on the Intellectual History of Innovation. Working Paper № 7. Montreal.
Griliches Z. (1962) Comment on W.R. Mueller's paper / NBER. The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press. P. 343-346.
Grossman G.M., Helpman E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Grossman G.M., Helpman E. (1994) Endogenous innovation in the theory of growth // Journal of Economic Perspectives. Vol. 8. № 1. P. 23-44.
Klevorick A.K., Levin R., Nelson R., Winter S. (1995) On the sources and significance of inter-industry differences in technological opportunities // Research Poliсy. Vol. 24. P. 185-205.
Lucas R.E. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development // Journal of Monetary Economics. Vol. 22. № 1. Р. 3-42.
Macilwain C. (2010) What science is really worth // Nature. Vol. 465. P. 682-684.
Martin F. (1998) The economic impact of Canadian university R&D // Research Policy. Vol. 27. P. 677-687.
Meyer-Kramer F., Schmoch U. (1998) Science-based technologies: university-industry interactions in four fields // Research Policy. Vol. 27. P. 835-851.
National Science Board (2010) Science and Engineering Indicators 2010 (NSB 10-01). Arlington, VA: National Science Foundation.
Nelson R. (1998) The agenda for growth theory: A different point of view // Cambridge Journal of Economics. Vol. 22. № 4. P. 497-520.
OECD (2002) Frascati Manual. Paris.
OECD (2010) Measuring Innovation. A new perspective. Paris.
Pavitt K. (1991) What makes basic research economically useful? // Research Policy. Vol. 20. P. 109-119.
Pavitt K. (1997) The Social Shaping of the National Science Base. SPRU Electronic Working Papers Series. Paper № 5.
Pavitt K. (2001) Public policies to support basic research: What can the rest of the world learn from US theory and practice? (And what they should not learn) // Industrial and Corporate Change. Vol. 10. № 3. Р. 761-779.
Romer P. (1994) The origins of endogenous growth // Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 98. № 5. Р. 71-102.
Rosenberg N. (1990) Why do firms do basic research (with their own money)? // Research Policy. Vol. 19. P. 165-174.
Rosenberg N., Nelson R. (1994) American universities and technical advance in industry // Research Policy. Vol. 23. P. 323-348.
Salter A., Martin B. (2001) The economic benefits of publicly funded basic research. A critical review // Research Policy. Vol. 30. P. 509-532.
Sanders B.S. (1962) Some difficulties in measuring inventive activity / NBER. The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press. P. 53-77.
Schibany A., Gassler H. (2010) Nutzen und Effekte der Grundlagenforschung. POLICIES Research Report № 98-2010 (im Auftrag des BMWF und des FWF). Wien: Joanneum Research.
Senker J. (1995) Tacit Knowledge and Models of Innovation // Journal of Industrial and Corporate Change. Vol. 4. P. 425-477.
Solow R.M. (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth // Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 70. P. 65-94.

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.